How to Make Rational, Transparent Pandemic Policy
Decision rules can help formalize the process by which leaders make choices.
How to Make Rational, Transparent Pandemic PolicyMatt Chase
Since the first COVID-19 vaccine was approved, the world has witnessed the fastest and most ambitious immunization campaign in human history. Scientists developed the vaccines at an unheard-of pace, and regulators approved their use with unprecedented speed.
Yet the production, distribution, and uptake of vaccinations has proceeded more slowly. While almost 65 percent of the global population had been inoculated, as of April, swathes of the world remained largely unvaccinated. Only 15 percent of people in low-income countries had received at least one dose. In the Democratic Republic of the Congo—the second-largest country in Africa, with 90 million citizens—less than 1 percent of the population was vaccinated. In Nigeria and Burkina Faso, the figure was about 10 percent. In Guatemala and Egypt, most people remained unvaccinated. Even in the United States, the world’s most powerful economy and the home to some of the biggest global pharmaceutical companies, almost one in five eligible people had not yet received a shot. In some areas of the US, this has delayed the national aim of achieving herd immunity, meaning that continued flare-ups may be more likely.
The challenges relate to both the supply of vaccines and the demand for them. While they were rolled out relatively quickly, they nevertheless had to be rationed at first, and production took some months to ramp up—which in part explains why it has taken so long to get poorer countries vaccinated. On the other hand, vaccine hesitancy, anti-vaccination campaigns, and misinformation have combined to suppress demand for vaccinations from those who are eligible.
The pandemic is still very much with us, but four critical lessons related to supply and demand have already emerged that could help us better respond to future outbreaks. Many of the data producing the underlying research come from the US and other rich economies, which have the resources to address a global pandemic. The lessons, if implemented, could improve our response to the next global public-health challenge.
Developing a drug in the US—from the lab to final approval—typically takes about 10 years. For example, Humira, the world’s best-selling prescription drug, traces its origins to a lab in Cambridge, United Kingdom, in 1991, and won approval in 2002 from the US Food and Drug Administration. Even an accelerated timetable, which has become more common in recent years, usually takes five to six years.
By contrast, the first COVID vaccine was approved, with Emergency Use Authorization, in less than a year, in part because researchers were already working on mRNA vaccine technology to combat coronaviruses. But it mainly reflects how authorities in the US, UK, and European Union slashed their traditional approvals timelines. Review and authorization times were rushed from months to days, waiting times between trials were scrapped, and ethics reviews were moved earlier in the process.
The anomaly between 10 years and one year raises eyebrows among many who are familiar with the traditional process and question not so much the safety of the COVID vaccines but the length of time it takes to get drugs approved, says Joshua P. Fairbank, an adjunct professor at Chicago Booth who cofounded a series of pharmaceutical companies.
“If the FDA and public-health officials believe that 9 months of safety data were enough to authorize the vaccine, and 15 months of data were enough to support mandates requiring vaccination, it would follow that the current system is inefficient, with significant room for improvement,” he says. “The spread between months and a decade is difficult to rationalize. We can use the COVID experience to improve the standard regulatory process. We should also use our decades of drug approval experience, including tragic mistakes, to rationally design an emergency authorization process now, before the next pandemic strikes.”
Rather than discussing whether to seize intellectual property and waive patents, countries should have been challenging companies to work with them to vaccinate the world fast.
Booth’s John R. Birge has been researching the drug development process in the US for more than a decade with an eye toward speeding it up. In research published in 2016, he and Southern Methodist University’s Vishal Ahuja (a graduate of Booth’s PhD Program) recommended cutting the drug approvals timeline by using adaptive trials, which would adjust the number of patients randomly assigned to treatment groups as information emerged about a drug’s effectiveness. (To learn more, read “How math can improve drug trials and save lives.”)
But the expedited greenlighting of the COVID vaccine indicates that the conventional final stage of approvals could be scaled back and combined with better postmarket surveillance after a drug’s public release, some of their more recent work suggests. Ahuja, Texas Tech’s Carlos Alvarez, Birge, and Booth’s Chad Syverson find that the relative lack of data collection that is necessary to speed vaccine approval could be remedied by conducting more rigorous surveys. “The FDA should be exhaustively canvassing vaccinated people to see what the severe adverse events have been, as opposed to the voluntary system we have now,” Birge says.
Their study looks at the diabetes drug rosiglitazone to determine whether the method that the FDA uses to assess and announce safety risks that arise after the agency has already approved a drug for use can hurt patients by scaring them away from treatment unnecessarily. In the case of rosiglitazone, after it was approved and released, studies linked the drug to heart problems. The FDA, in line with its current practice, kept the drug on the market but issued a warning designed to call attention to life-threatening risks. Consequently, most doctors and patients dropped the drug, and few resumed using it even after additional studies indicated the drug was safe and the FDA eliminated its warning.
While the FDA was seeking to keep patients apprised of newly identified health risks, it ended up deterring many people who would have benefited from using the drug, argue the researchers, who identify several weaknesses in the agency’s postmarket surveillance systems that can cause high error rates. They propose an approach grounded in statistics and economics that the FDA could use to independently validate any safety signals and better catch and assess risks that do turn up. (For more about this research, read “A new approach to ensuring drugs are safe.”)
The same issues surrounding data collection apply to the rollout of the COVID vaccine, Birge notes. The FDA is not currently collecting information needed to adequately assess the side effects of each COVID vaccine, even though the safety bar was lowered significantly in order to expedite vaccine approvals. “The current system is effectively anecdotal and does not systematically try to assess whether serious adverse events are occurring in those who are treated,” he says.
And beyond the coronavirus, combining long-term data collection with adaptive trials conducted before a drug’s release could cut years from the approvals process, he adds. It could slash the cost of development and save untold lives by bringing critical medicines to market faster. Thus, some regulatory changes inspired by this pandemic could potentially lead to better outcomes in a future pandemic, and in more normal times too.
After COVID vaccines began to be approved in late 2020, the industry responded quickly, producing 11.2 billion doses in 2021. Today, wealthy countries have more than 1 billion surplus vaccine doses.
But had the industry increased supply even faster, the US might have achieved widespread vaccination four months earlier than it did (in March 2021 rather than July 2021), and more of the rest of the world might be vaccinated too, according to research by a team including Chicago Booth’s Eric Budish and Canice Prendergast. (For more, read “Why the world needs a lot more vaccine capacity.”) A few months may sound insignificant, but the researchers, drawing on calculations by Harvard’s David M. Cutler and Lawrence H. Summers, estimate the global harm wrought by the pandemic to have been about $1 trillion a month until vaccination started.
The key to a better ramp-up, Budish says, is more government outlay and a genuine partnership with the companies that invent vaccines. Essentially, Budish thinks the world, and rich countries in particular, should have invested more, earlier in working with companies to construct production facilities that might never have come online. Early on in the pandemic, the US initially headed in this direction but was ultimately too timid and invested only around one-tenth of what was likely necessary, he says, while other countries did even less. Had governments put more money into this “capacity at risk,” pharmaceutical companies could have had more factories ready to go as soon as their vaccine was approved. Given the high price of the pandemic, this added speed would have warranted the cost to the US and other governments of potentially paying for redundant capacity.
Then, says Budish, once vaccines were shown to work, governments should have invested exponentially more in production and distribution. Rather than discussing whether to seize intellectual property and waive patents—a conversation that he views as an excuse to avoid spending—countries should have been challenging companies to work with them to vaccinate the world fast. Budish notes that at a rough price of $50 per shot, vaccinating 5 billion people worldwide costs $250 billion. As governments have to spend that money anyway, he would have preferred that figure to have been used up front as an incentive to pharmaceutical companies to build production capacity on an industrial scale.
“The conversation I wish had happened was, ‘We would like to vaccinate the world in six months, with 5 billion courses of mRNA. Please submit some proposals—and we’re willing to pay up to $250 billion for it,’” he says. “You might get nothing credible, but then you at least learn what’s possible.”
Adopting a problem-solving partnership with pharmaceutical companies could, Budish suggests, prove a more efficient and effective path to vaccinating large numbers of people next time we need to do so.
During the pandemic, vaccines took on a political significance in the US as never before. While some Americans posted images of their vaccination cards online, others railed against vaccine mandates. Some expounded elaborate conspiracy theories about government tracking devices being implanted in unwary people.
But vaccine hesitancy, rather than vaccine rejection, perhaps better explains the slow uptake of inoculation. Only 12–16 percent of US residents said over the past year that they would “definitely not” get vaccinated, according to an ongoing monthly Kaiser Family Foundation survey. Many people found themselves in the middle, wary of fake news but unsure about the vaccine’s safety. Between February 2021 and February 2022, the percentage saying they would get vaccinated only if required to do so shrank from 7 percent to 3 percent, and the “wait and see” crowd fell from 22 percent to 4 percent of the population.
One reason for vaccine hesitancy cited by many scholars is higher-than-average levels of distrust in the government and medical profession among the US’s Black and Hispanic communities. Many observers trace this to unethical medical episodes such as the infamous Tuskegee experiments of 1932–72, in which Black men infected with syphilis were recruited on the promise of free medical care but were then deliberately denied treatment and given placebos. Vaccine hesitancy among historically marginalized groups is particularly concerning since COVID disproportionately hits these communities in the US.
More generally, elevated concerns about vaccine safety were perhaps predictable given the accelerated approvals process. Omission bias is a behavioral tendency that favors doing nothing over taking an action that is potentially harmful, even when doing nothing is also harmful. Worried that getting inoculated for COVID is riskier than taking a medicine approved via the conventional route, many people have opted to go unvaccinated.
Identifying and addressing the appetite for risk in this context could help reduce vaccine hesitancy, according to research by Vanderbilt’s Jennifer S. Trueblood, Booth’s Abigail Sussman, and Booth postdoctoral scholar Daniel O’Leary. The researchers find a correlation between financial-risk aversion and vaccine hesitancy. The more appetite participants in their study had for financial risk, the more likely they were to be open to getting vaccinated. (For more on this research, read “Financial-risk preferences predict vaccine acceptance.”)
“For the most part, they’re trying to solve for community-level outcomes, but they’re talking about individual-level risk. There’s a mismatch between the solution they are targeting and what they are communicating.”
—Abigail Sussman
In the second part of their paper, the researchers found a way to sway more risk-averse people—by reframing the issue in terms of the social and communal benefits of vaccines rather than as one of individual risk. They randomly assigned 1,003 online participants, recruited from Amazon’s Mechanical Turk, to read one of four messages about a hypothetical COVID vaccine. Participants in a control group received general information about the FDA’s vaccine approval process and the vaccine’s efficacy and potential side effects. Those in the other groups received the same information, as well as further details that stressed either the individual benefit of getting vaccinated, the social benefit, or both.
After reading, participants reported how soon they would be willing to take the vaccine once it became available. Those whose attention had been focused on the community were willing to get the shot significantly sooner.
Sussman says that while the researchers didn’t track official public-health announcements during the pandemic, her sense is that messaging campaigns tended to focus on individual rather than social benefits. For example, the Centers for Disease Control and Prevention page explaining the benefits of vaccination focuses on communicating that the COVID vaccine is a safe and effective way to build protection against the virus for oneself. Sussman says, “For the most part, they’re trying to solve for community-level outcomes, but they’re talking about individual-level risk. There’s a mismatch between the solution they are targeting and what they are communicating.”
The research suggests that focusing more on social benefits in public-health messaging could help to reduce vaccine hesitancy when we face future outbreaks.
Aside from tweaking the message, a key way to help people overcome their fears may simply be to pay them to receive the vaccine, as many countries, cities, and states have done around the globe.
Early on in the pandemic, economists suggested paying people a significant sum to get vaccinated. Robert E. Litan, a nonresident senior fellow at the Brookings Institution, proposed giving Americans $1,000 each to get vaccinated. His proposal was backed by Harvard’s N. Gregory Mankiw in a New York Times op-ed.
But critics said the plan would be perverse and coercive. “It is deeply problematic that the government would offer cash incentives to promote vaccination when it has failed, in numerous instances throughout this pandemic, to offer money or other supports needed to ensure that the basic needs of many people are being met,” argued Emily A. Largent of the University of Pennsylvania Perelman School of Medicine and Franklin G. Miller of Weill Cornell Medical College in January 2021.
While the $1,000 payment was never implemented, a patchwork of pay-to-vaccinate schemes developed across the US. West Virginia paid some of its residents $100 to get a shot, Maryland did the same for state employees, and Colorado paid $500 to Department of Corrections employees who got fully vaccinated. Dozens of states offered tickets for lotteries with prizes ranging from millions of dollars in cash to free college tuition and luxury vacations.
Research by a team including Chicago Booth’s Devin G. Pope suggests that these large sum payments would have been effective and, in fact, even a small amount of money can demonstrably increase willingness to be vaccinated. Among a group of 8,300 participants in Sweden from May to July 2021, vaccination rates went from 72 percent to 76 percent after a 200 kronor payment (approximately US$24) incentivizing participants to get one shot. The increase was seen across socioeconomic groups. The research also tested whether behavioral “nudges” could boost rates and find that although these increased participants’ intention to get vaccinated, they didn’t have a meaningful effect on actual vaccination rates. (For more on this research, read “Does paying people to get vaccinated work?”)
In Sweden, a small incentive paid to anyone who received the COVID-19 vaccine significantly increased uptake. But in Philadelphia, a lottery offering large prizes did not.
Pope’s research touches on a long-standing debate in psychology and economics over the use of financial incentives to shape behavior. Essentially, critics of paying people to perform an action have argued that these payments could backfire by damaging people’s intrinsic motivation. Once people start to associate an activity with earning money, they think about it in a different way, and if the money is removed, they may be reluctant to continue the activity unless they are paid again, a critique psychologists term motivation crowding theory. Donors paid to give blood, for example, may stop doing so if the payments are halted, even if they might have previously given blood without getting paid.
But others argue the situation is more nuanced—for example, it’s possible a person donating blood may stop doing so, but only temporarily. (For more on this concept, read “Short-term rewards don’t sap long-term motivation.”)
In further research that studies paying people to get vaccinated, Pope and his coauthors quash any concerns about crowding out the desire to get a second shot. The researchers find that the people who were paid to get vaccinated in the first Swedish study were even more likely than average to receive a second vaccination shot, even though they were no longer paid for it.
To Pope, this is evidence that concerns over the unintended consequences of paying people to get vaccinated may be overblown. “My take from both our paper and the broader literature on using financial incentives to motivate healthy and prosocial behavior is that it almost never backfires,” Pope says.
This is not to say that financial incentives always work. Pope and Booth’s Richard H. Thaler (a Nobel laureate) were part of a team of researchers led by University of Pennsylvania’s Katherine L. Milkman that tested whether offering lottery tickets for vaccinations could raise inoculation rates. They set up three geographically targeted lotteries of up to $50,000, but find that the prizes did not significantly nor sustainably raise vaccination rates.
Instead, Pope says, consistent and relatively small universal payments could help keep the coronavirus under control, since regular booster shots are certain to be part of the solution. “Offering people $100 every year if they take their booster, that would have a pretty big effect,” he says. It’s a strategy officials could implement in the future—or right now.
Decision rules can help formalize the process by which leaders make choices.
How to Make Rational, Transparent Pandemic PolicyA resumption of commercial activity without the return of childcare could add a new dimension to economic inequality.
More Than 50 Million Americans Can’t Return to Work Fully until Schools ReopenChicago Booth's Haresh Sapra says that at a time when lending is crucial to keeping companies afloat, we should be careful not to repeat our past mistakes.
Why Current Accounting Rules Could Stop Banks from LendingYour Privacy
We want to demonstrate our commitment to your privacy. Please review Chicago Booth's privacy notice, which provides information explaining how and why we collect particular information when you visit our website.