Inequality may be the economic issue of the moment, but the theme has long preoccupied economists. In 1919, Irving Fisher, a giant in early 20th-century economics, warned of “a bitter struggle over the distribution of wealth until a . . . definite readjustment has been found.”
Simon Kuznets (who went on to win a Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences in 1971) took a more sanguine view in 1954, during the post–World War II boom. He found that economic growth reduced income inequality in rich countries, but had the opposite effect in poorer countries.
The 2007–10 financial crisis and the economic downturn that accompanied it focused attention on longer-term trends in wealth and income inequality around the world. The debate intensified following the publication last year of Capital in the Twenty-First Century by Thomas Piketty of the Paris School of Economics. The dense, nearly 700-page tome quickly became a global publishing sensation, spending almost six months on the New York Times best-seller list and being named business book of the year by the Financial Times.
The debate has drawn in a host of world-class economists, among them Chicago Booth faculty Kevin M. Murphy, George J. Stigler Distinguished Service Professor of Economics, and Robert H. Topel, Isidore Brown and Gladys J. Brown Distinguished Service Professor; and Claudia Goldin and Lawrence F. Katz of Harvard.
The data clearly indicate that the divide between the wealthy and everyone else has greatly increased over the past four decades. In 2012, the top 1 percent of US households took in 22.5 percent of household income; in 1979, they got a mere 10 percent of the pie, according to the Pew Research Center. The research group noted in December 2014 that the typical upper-income US household now holds nearly seven times the wealth of a middle-income household—the largest gap in 30 years of available records. (Upper-income households are defined as having income of at least $132,000 for a family of four, while a middle-income household is defined as having income of $44,000 to $132,000 for a family of four.) Meanwhile, by one measure, real median household income, around $51,900, is about where it was in 1995, according to the Federal Reserve Bank of Saint Louis.
Middle-class incomes have stagnated in many developed countries. A study by the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development finds that income inequality increased in 17 of 22 members, mainly developed countries, between 1985 and 2008.
That widening gap between rich and poor has become a hot-button political issue. Over the past two years, more than a dozen US cities and counties, including Chicago; San Diego; San Jose, California; and Washington, DC, have hiked their minimum wages in the belief that such policies would reduce income inequality. Seattle and San Francisco will raise their base wages to $15 an hour by 2018.
Does capital outpace income?
Beginning in the 1990s, Piketty, Emmanuel Saez of the University of California, Berkeley, and others have assembled a formidable set of tax and income data for more than 20 countries, which has helped them trace patterns in income inequality going back 100 years.
Piketty’s central idea is simple: the rich get richer while the poor stay poor. “Money tends to reproduce itself,” he writes in Capital. According to his argument, inequality expands when capital—the combination of physical assets such as land, factories, and equipment, and financial assets such as profits, dividends, and interest—grows faster than the underlying economy that supports it. He argues that these conditions held in the 19th century, and he predicts they will return in the 21st.
Piketty, who often criticizes American economists’ reliance on equations, expresses that dynamic in simple algebra: r>g, where r is the return on capital and g is economic growth. Piketty pegs the historical return on capital at 4–5 percent a year and growth at 1.5 percent per annum, a figure he believes won’t increase much because of low population growth.
“In a quasi-stagnant society, wealth accumulated in the past will inevitably acquire disproportionate importance,” he writes. “Decreased growth—especially demographic growth—is thus responsible for capital’s [dominance].” Piketty’s equation implies that under these circumstances, nothing can stop even greater income inequality—nothing save government intervention, which he advocates via a global wealth tax.
He believes that the class and wealth division in society now “appears to be comparable in magnitude to that observed in Europe in 1900–1910” and might one day approach the disparities of the early 1800s. That was when great writers such as Jane Austen and Honoré de Balzac, whom Piketty cites frequently in Capital, poignantly depicted their characters’ desperation to attain titles and income from inherited wealth far beyond what they could earn at a trade or profession.
It is, at heart, a pessimistic view of the free-market system, reminiscent of the inherent “contradictions” that Karl Marx believed would destroy capitalism. (Piketty frequently criticizes Marx, but his title is an homage to the revolutionary economist’s own unfinished Das Kapital.)
Is Piketty right? Does the nature of capitalism itself doom us to perpetual inequality? Or do the roots of inequality lie elsewhere, so that it might be possible to raise the income of the many rather than merely tax away the wealth of the rich?