Education can affect a child’s lifetime earning power—and that, of course, costs money. So when a family has multiple children and financial limitations, parents often face a decision about how to invest their educational funds.
While they might not articulate their decision as an economist might, they have several options, economically-speaking. They may seek to maximize their investment in their children, by spending money in a way that will return the most in terms of future income. Alternatively, they could spend an equal amount on each child, or they could spend more on the child that’s further behind to help that child earn the same amount as their sibling one day.
Which option do families most frequently choose? Research by the University of Delaware’s James Berry, Chicago Booth’s Rebecca Dizon-Ross, and University of Colorado Denver’s Maulik Jagnani finds that parents demonstrate a strong interest in treating their children equally.
The researchers worked with 300 families in rural Malawi who had at least two children in grades five to seven, telling them that two of their children would take a math test and would receive monetary awards on the basis of their scores. But parents were also given 10 lottery tickets and told one of those tickets, randomly selected, would provide an hour of tutoring for one child. The parents had to allocate the tickets between their children.
In general, parents who care only about maximizing returns should invest more in whichever child, whether high or low ability, they think will produce the greatest return on investment, the researchers note.
By contrast, parents who care most about their children earning equally should initially allocate resources toward the lower-ability child, the idea being that this child can catch up with the higher-ability child in earning potential.
And those concerned with investment equality should allocate resources—including money and time—equally to each child, regardless of their abilities and the outcome. In the experiment, any result besides an “all or nothing” distribution demonstrates concern about investment equality, the researchers write. That’s because parents unconcerned with investment equality should in theory allocate all the tickets to the child they believe will generate the higher returns from tutoring.
Before the parents allocated their tickets, they were asked to answer questions about their children’s abilities. How did they think each child would score on the test without tutoring, and how might that score change with tutoring?