I recently watched Free Solo, the great movie about rock climber Alex Honnold’s free solo (no aids, no ropes, no protection at all) climb of El Capitan in Yosemite National Park. Among many other things, it got me thinking about economic growth.
The abilities of contemporary rock climbers are far beyond those of climbers just a generation ago. The Wikipedia history of El Capitan starts with a 47-day climb in 1958—which used pitons, ropes, and all sorts of equipment—and continues through development of routes and techniques to Alex’s three-hour romp up the face.
Why weren’t such climbs done long ago? There is essentially no technology involved. OK, Honnold wears modern climbing boots, which have very sticky rubber. But that’s about it. And reasonably sticky rubber has been around for a hundred years or so too.
There is nothing technological that stopped human beings from climbing in much this way centuries ago. Honnold, transported to 1890, might not have free soloed El Capitan without his current boots, but he would have climbed a lot more big walls than anyone else.
Clearly, there has been an explosion in human ability to climb rocks, just as there has been in human productivity, or our knowledge of how to do things, in more prosaic and more economic activities.
In studying economic growth, we (and especially those of us in Silicon Valley) focus way too much on gadgets and too little on simple human knowledge. Southwest Airlines’ ability to get an airliner back in the air in half the time it took in the 1970s (and still does at many larger airlines) is as much about an increase in productivity as it is about installing the latest gadget. Growth is about the knowledge of how to do things, knowledge that is only sometimes embodied in machines. Free Solo is a great example of the expansion of ability, driven purely by advances in knowledge, untethered from machines.
How did it happen? The radical improvements in rock climbing that led to Honnold’s achievement display the same patterns as economic growth theorists tell us about.
Knowledge externalities: When one person learns how to do something, and when he or she can and does communicate that knowledge to others, the others can quickly benefit from that knowledge, and the group advances.
Honnold, like Isaac Newton, climbed on the shoulders of giants. Just how do you get up El Capitan? There are now many established routes—successions of incredibly tiny holes, cracks, and ledges in a 3,000-foot face of rock that experienced climbers figured out how to stitch together. Honnold didn’t have to figure all that out, as he chose an established route.
Likewise, nobody in 1958 had any idea that you could hang by your thumbs and fingers to exploit little pieces of rock. This knowledge, demonstrated in the movie, emerged from the community of rock climbers and boulderers over time. Honnold is incredibly good at it, but he learned from others.
Knowledge transmission: Everyone is all upset about intellectual property (IP) these days, but nobody patents rock-climbing techniques. (There is some patentable technology in the devices people use to climb with ropes, and that has enabled free climbing, but it’s really not central.) The knowledge gets produced, which is costly to the individual producing it, and then passed on, where it is much easier to learn than it is to innovate, and the whole group gets better.