Should central banks offset trade wars? Given that the United States has started a trade war, and given that the Federal Reserve, the European Central Bank, and other central banks are easing monetary policy to offset trade headwinds, it’s a question that bears consideration.
Central banks, including the Fed and the ECB, seem to take for granted that any reduction in economic activity, including a trade-war-induced slowdown, demands offsetting monetary stimulus. But stimulus can only provide aggregate demand. What if the problem is aggregate supply? What if an economy is humming along at full demand, and then someone throws a wrench in the works, be it a trade war, a bad tax code, or a regulatory onslaught, and that supply shock causes a slowdown?
Conventional wisdom says that central banks should not offset reductions in aggregate supply. The first job of a central bank should be to distinguish demand shocks from supply shocks, so it can react to the former but not to the latter. This standard wisdom emanates from the 1970s, when central banks kept rates low to offset the effects of oil price shocks—supply shocks—and ended up producing worse recessions and inflation.
When I express this once-standard view at central banks these days, people stare at me with blank expressions. Distinguish supply from demand shocks? Why would we do that? Central bankers seem to assume that all fluctuations in output, employment, and prices come from demand. Yet this 1960s-era Keynesian view should have died a long time ago. Surely some shocks come from supply, not demand?
The Fed—like the ECB—is pursuing looser policy, and is pretty clearly fighting trade-war headwinds. On August 1, the Fed lowered its target for the federal funds rate by 25 basis points, the first such decline since 2008. It lowered the target by a further 25 basis points on September 19, “in light of the implications of global developments for the economic outlook,” as well as flagging inflation.