Free trade is a whipping boy for some politicians of late. US President Donald Trump has pulled out of trade partnerships, Britain has been negotiating its exit from the European Union, and a trade war is intensifying. But most economists argue that trade liberalization is a good thing that can benefit all parties. And research by Chicago Booth’s Chang-Tai Hsieh, Stanford’s Peter J. Klenow, and University of Chicago PhD candidate Ishan Nath finds the benefits of free trade could be even bigger than realized.
The researchers examined data from Canadian and US manufacturers before and after the 1988 US-Canada Free Trade Agreement, which was replaced by the North American Free Trade Agreement in 1994. They studied the relationship between changing tariffs and the rate of creative destruction—the late political economist Joseph Schumpeter’s term for the process of destroying one economic structure while creating a new one. Creative destruction is on display when companies shift resources from one area of production to another, or when competitors with a better product drive out incumbents. This is the process through which economic growth happens—although it also causes the sort of job reallocation that can be devastating to individuals and communities, which is what has made trade so controversial.
Hence, there’s an inherent trade-off. Say a country’s trade is limited and its computer-chip manufacturers dominate the domestic market. A freer approach to trade would give these chip companies more opportunity to sell in international markets but would also expose them to global competition. If they are competitive, their businesses could grow. If they aren’t, they could be knocked out of the market.
Most economic models describe what happens as a one-time shock to the economy—if domestic chip makers can’t compete, their workers lose jobs and hopefully shift into a more competitive industry. But Hsieh, Klenow, and Nath argue that trade causes long-term effects, not one-time shifts, as it exposes companies to innovation and ideas. Companies that innovate create jobs, while companies that are “innovated upon” do more firing than hiring, according to the researchers’ model. Domestic chip makers that face global competition might learn more about their competitors’ products and processes, and improve their own products and processes as a result. Those that don’t improve would go out of business.
The model demonstrates that less-innovative countries reap the largest share of the benefits involved from this process, gaining ideas from their more-innovative trading partners. “A country that innovates less benefits more from trade liberalization since it is now easier for the country to ‘import’ ideas,” the researchers write. But they also find that lower tariffs promote the introduction and eventual dominance of better-quality products on both sides of a border, which can be a catalyst for economic growth.