How Robots Damaged the American Dream
A study looks at the effects of automation in the 21st century.
How Robots Damaged the American DreamMaximizing shareholder value, the central mission of many corporate boards across the United States, has become a handy defense for questionable business decisions. In the past year alone, corporate directors have cited “a fiduciary duty” to make the most possible money for shareholders as justification for cutting large numbers of jobs, price gouging patients in need of lifesaving drugs, and investing in projects that harm the environment.
Two prominent economists challenge this justification by arguing that directors have a fiduciary duty to maximize shareholders’ welfare, not value. Many shareholders buy more-expensive electric cars or they may pay more for fair-trade coffee because they care about some social objective, the researchers note. “Why would they not want the companies they invest in to do the same?” the researchers ask.
In fact, in privately held companies, owners give up some profits to achieve their social goals: reduce pollution, provide affordable medicines to people, protect their workers, etc. In other terms, they sacrifice profits to support their social values.
Oliver Hart, a Nobel laureate at Harvard University, and Chicago Booth’s Luigi Zingales, argue that publicly traded companies should do this, too, as long as they have the approval of their shareholders. Their reasoning has the same starting point as the late Milton Friedman’s: corporations should conduct business according to their shareholders’ “desires.” Friedman, a University of Chicago economist and Nobel laureate, defined this desire as “making as much money as possible while conforming to basic rules of society.” In other words, Friedman implicitly assumed that shareholders care only about profits. He saw his blunt directive for profits as a way to protect public companies from the self-interests of the people who run them. Unlike conserving the environment or chasing other ideological pursuits, earning profits and raising share prices are universal goals among investors. The broader ethical limits of the pursuit are best left to government regulators, according to the economist’s New York Times essay on the subject in 1970. Forty-seven years later, thousands of corporations have enshrined the profits-foremost philosophy in their mission statements.
The Equation: How to maximize shareholder welfare
Yet if we allow for the possibility that shareholders are prosocial, the duty to maximize shareholders’ welfare, not value, follows naturally, argue Hart and Zingales. But what about a case in which only some shareholders are prosocial, how should a company behave? The researchers suggest that in this case, asking shareholders for their opinions would have no downsides: if shareholders only care about profits, they will strike down any proposal that would reduce profits for a social objective. If they care about some social objectives, a vote will make it possible to achieve some of these objectives. Furthermore, a shareholders’ vote would alleviate Friedman’s concerns about self-interested managers. The social objective would not be decided unilaterally by managers, but agreed upon.
Oliver Hart and Luigi Zingales, “Companies Should Maximize Shareholder Welfare Not Market Value,” Working paper, July 2017.
A study looks at the effects of automation in the 21st century.
How Robots Damaged the American DreamOne idea for helping consumers avoid debt traps didn’t work in a UK experiment, partly because people didn’t have the funds.
Paying Off Credit-Card Debt May Take More Than a NudgeChicago Booth’s Sendhil Mullainathan visits the podcast to discuss if AI is really “intelligent” and whether a profit motive is always bad.
Capitalisn’t: Who Controls AI?Your Privacy
We want to demonstrate our commitment to your privacy. Please review Chicago Booth's privacy notice, which provides information explaining how and why we collect particular information when you visit our website.